IRAQ-KUWAIT AND NUTTY THINKING ABOUT ENERGY The Iraq-Kuwait rise in oil prices has triggered the inevitable silly season in energy pronouncements. Some call for rationing and price control that would create gas lines and petty racketeering. Others lament the lack of a national energy "plan" that would surely twist energy industries into knots, and eventually reduce supply and raise prices. But the nuttiest are those who use this event as the hook on which to hang the call for a return to a "simpler life" in order to save the supply of energy. A clutch of well-known biologists and "ecologists," and even a few economists, would have us waste our time and effort, slow the progress of civilization, and cripple the economy in order to mitigate a shortage of energy that they speculate will finish us off starting perhaps seven billion years from now. (Yes, you read right. That's 7,000,000,000 years.) They write fearfully about an increase in "entropy" -- a disappearance of order and a disintegration of all patterns of life into chaos. Yet the trend is just the opposite. Over the decades and centuries, energy is becoming less rather than more scarce, just like all other raw materials such as copper and land. Human life becomes better organized rather than more disordered. And there is no reason to believe that this trend will ever reverse. Instead, this benign trend can go on forever. Governmentally- mandated conservation of energy would only be a drag on this progress. The historical facts entirely contradict the commonsensical Malthusian theory that the more we use, the less there is left to use, and hence the greater the scarcity. Through the centuries, the prices of energy -- coal, oil, and electricity -- have been decreasing rather than increasing, relative to the cost of labor and even relative to the price of consumer goods, just as with all other natural resources. And nuclear energy costs less than either coal or oil. In economic terms, this means that energy has been getting more available, rather than more scarce, as far back as we have data. This implies that the rate at which our stocks of resources increase, or increasing efficiency of use, or a combination of the two forces, have overmatched the exhaustion of resources. Another way to look at the matter: energy has become less and less important as measured by its share of GNP. This is the same story as revealed by all other natural resources. For perspective, reflect on the history of another resource that people have worried about since time immemorial: land. It has always seemed as obvious as the nose on your face that the supposedly-fixed supply of agricultural land must eventually limit the growth of population, and must make food increasingly more expensive as the number of people increases on Earth. But lo and behold, just the opposite has happened. Food has decreased in price, nutrition has become progressively more abundant, and hunger and famine have diminished worldwide, even as population has grown. The explanation lies in the advance in knowledge of how to produce food. Just as people throughout history have said that the supply of land is limited and cannot be increased, many people have said that the energy-cost trend must turn around sometime because energy is "finite." And they have gone on to assert that we should build a new system of economics upon energy as a standard of value. (Here they resemble Marx and his labor theory of value in seeking a material standard of value, a solid physical foundation on which to stand. The reason that the prices of energy and other natural resources decline even as we use more is the advance of technology. Energy differs from other resources because it is "used up," and cannot be recycled. Energy apparently trends toward exhaustion. It seems impossible to keep using energy and still never run out of it, or even reach a point of increasing scarcity. But just as with land and copper, there are other forces at play which make it possible for us to have increasing amounts of the services we need even as we boost the demands we make upon the supplies of those resources. One saving grace is declining use of energy. Consider the steam engine, which at first operated at perhaps 1 percent efficiency. Engines nowadays operate perhaps thirty times more efficiently. That is, they use perhaps a thirtieth as much energy for the same result. When someone finds a way to increase the efficiency of a resource by, say, 1 percent, the discovery not only increases the efficiency of the energy we use this year, but it also increases the effective stock of all amounts of that resource in stock or as yet undiscovered. And this process could continue a long time, perhaps indefinitely. Also important are increases in energy supply. We learn how to dig deeper, pump faster. And we invent new sources of energy -- aside from coal, shale, tar sounds, and the like. We can also "grow" oil substitutes as long as there is sunlight to raise plants. And nuclear fission power will be available at constant or declining costs practically forever. And who knows, there may be nuclear fusion, or some other suns to take care of our needs after this one runs out. We've got seven billion years to discover solutions to the theoretical problems that we have only been able to cook up in the past few centuries of progress in physics. It's reasonable to expect the supply of energy to continue becoming more available, forever. Julian L. Simon teaches business administration at the University of Maryland, and is the author most recently of Population Matters: People, Resources, Environment, and Immigration published by Transaction Press and Hudson Institute. page 1/article0 eneroped/October 1, 1990