IMMIGRATION COST-BENEFIT, THEN AND NOW Julian L. Simon and Rita James Simon Immigration is worrying the public again. Sanctions against illegal immigrants passed through Congress in 1986. Now legislation to "reform" legal immigration has passed in the Senate and is coming up for debate in the House. The key element is a "cap" to restrict total immigration, though special-interest issues distract attention from the cap. The Founding Fathers were sure of the value of immigration. One of the Declaration of Independence's complaints against King George III was that he hindered the peopling of the colonies from abroad. He has endeavored to prevent the population of these States; for that purpose obstructing the Laws for Naturalization of foreigners; refusing to pass others to encourage their migration better, and raising the conditions of new appropriation of Lands. And James Madison wrote: "[T]hat part of America which has encouraged the foreigner most has advanced the most rapidly in population, agriculture and the arts." Yet public opinion has always opposed immigration. The passions, arguments, and public opinion are the same now as always, eerily identical throughout our history. In the first half of the 19th century, the Irish immigrants in New York and Boston were seen as the unassimilable possessors of all bad qualities. One newspaper wrote: "America has become the sewer into which the pollutions of European jails are emptied." And another: "Have we not a right to protect ourselves against the ravenous dregs of anarchy and crime, the tainted swarms of pauperism and vice Europe shakes on our shores from her diseased robes?" The 1884 platform of the Democratic party stated its opposition to the "importation of foreign labor or the admission of servile races unfitted by habit, training, religion or kindred for absorption into the great body of our people or for the citizenship which our laws confer." [Out?] [Francis Walker, Commissioner General of the Immigration Service, and first president of the American Economic Association, wrote in June 1896: The question today is ... protecting the American rate of wages, the American standard of living, and the quality of American citizenship from degradation through the tumultuous access of vast throngs of ignorant and brutalized peasantry from the countries of Eastern and Southern Europe. He cautioned: The entrance into our political, social and industrial life of such vast masses of peasantry, degraded below our utmost conceptions, is a matter which no intelligent patriot can look upon without the gravest apprehension and alarm.] Right through the 1930's, these views were expressed about immigrants in national media such as The Saturday Evening Post. And polls since the 1930's consistently show that a majority of Americans are against immigration. The attitude in each generation may be characterized as: The immigrants who came in the past were good folk. But the ones coming now are scum. The economics of immigration are better understood now than before, however. Emma Lazarus's poem at the base of the Statue of Liberty did harm by fostering a false impression about the economic nature of immigrants. She wrote about "huddled masses" and "wretched refuse." But immigrants generally are not tired, poor, "huddled masses;" they are not "wretched refuse." Rather, they are usually young and vigorous adults, well-educated and highly skilled, with excellent earnings potential. Even when Ms. Lazarus wrote her heartwarming poem, immigrants compared favorably with the native population in occupational skill. P.J. Hil interest rate would change at all, let alone magically have the change of the required size. So again the monetized K/Y ratio remains the same while the physical relationship changes. For labor's share the argument is similar to that for the interest rate. Assume for now that labor's share is increasing, by say 5% or l5%. But the largest possible increase is from, say, 66% to lOO% of all income. Even if this change were induced by some change in physical capital efficiency (physical output per dollar of capital cost, in a case where labor remains the same), it could not offset some of the really big changes in capital efficiency that we see (e.g., in computers). And there is no reason to see labor's share change as induced, anyway. So the constancy of labor's share is not crucial to the argument, but rather is necessary only to argue it with neat and simple algebra. IV. THE REAL COURSE OF THE PHYSICAL K/Y RATIO Now that we have seen that there is no empirical reason in the observed monetary K/Y ratios to believe that the physical K/Y ratio is constant, we are free to theorize about the course of the physical K/Y ratio as economic development proceeds. This section is entirely dispensable; one might judge that it were better omitted from the paper. But there may be some others who will think that this discussion of physical K/Y ratios is illuminating rather than obfuscating, and therefore it is included. I repeat that one may choose not to engage in this speculation at all, a position that is perfectly consistent with one implication of this paper, that is, that a growth model may imply a decreasing K/Y ratio; one can simply ignore the K/Y ratio completely. But it seems to me that such speculation is at least interesting even if it has no implication, because it illuminates the process of economic development. A falling physical capital-output ratio would seem an obvious technological fact. But to show this rigorously we must proceed in step-by-step fashion, making only those comparisons that can legitimately be made. This means that we cannot compare entire capital stocks, largely because new consumer products are introduced with the passage of time. Any useful comparisons must be between units of capital that are similar in at least some fashion. I propose that two machines be considered similar capital for the purposes of the discussion here if they produce identical output. (There can be no reasonable way of objectively comparing various kinds of capital making different products. That is at the root of my argument and supports it: If there is no hope of creating an objective measure of such capital, it is not meaningful to make statements about the physical relationship of capital to an equally-impossible-to- measure-objectively physical measure of aggregate output.) Let us begin with identical tools used to make identical products at different moments of history. Consider the important example of farmland. A given acre of Pennsylvania land produces --even after other physical inputs are allowed for--a much larger amount of corn now than in earlier years. And if a Pennsylvania- Dutch Amish farmer chooses to work with horses, the horses together with the Pennsylvania land produce more output per acre and per horse (with equal or less man hours) than in previous years. And there is no reason not to attribute this increased output-capital ratio to labor-augmenting technological progress-- better calendars, better knowledge of hybrid seeds, information about optimal planting depths, improvements in motive power, and so on. Or take the homely example of the claw hammer, which has changed little in form for many years; the amount of fastening that a carpenter does in a day with a claw hammer has risen considerably over the years because of improvements in nails, materials to be fastened, materials transportation, and so on. Still other examples: With the same endowment of human legs we get faster miles run, higher heights jumped, and longer distances leaped, due to better knowledge of track techniques and training methods (but hopefully not because of new drugs). With the same ox or baby we now get more lifetime days of work due to better knowledge of nutrition and disease prevention. We build the same house with less stone, due to advanced civil engineering knowledge of stresses. The same must be true of almost every tool that we now use, unchanged from earlier years, to produce the same output. And for most of these tools additional uses have been discovered over the years, which can only be interpreted as a reduction in the capital-output ratio. If one were to consider tools for the same purpose that have im- proved over the years--diesel locomotives compared to steam locomotives or horses--the comparison is more strained, yet it suggests even more strongly an increased technological output- capital ratio. If a farmer replaces a team of horses with a tractor that uses the same number of man-hours, then implicit in the replacement decision is that the new capital dominates the old, in the Pareto sense of having a higher output/capital ratio, and for this farmer the price of output may be taken as constant with respect to this decision. Unless the tractor purpose also causes a decrease in man-hours (which raises the issue of relative prices) the shift to the tractor may be seen immediately as a reduction in the capital-output ratio. For much of the capital stock the choice does involve relative cost valuations of labor and capital, however, and much other capital produces goods and services that were not produced in the past. Hence pairwise technological compal analyzed immigrants' wages and occupations in censuses and other data sources from 1840 to 1920, with special attention to the 1890's, and concluded that "immigrants, instead of being an underpaid, exploited group, generally held an economic position that compared very favorably to that of the native born members of the society." And Bernard Bailyn's research on the colonial-period Registry of Emigrants from Great Britain reveals that immigrants had excellent economic characteristics, being mainly young "useful artisans" and farmers. Today, too, the economic "quality" of immigrants is high compared to that of natives. Immigrants are mainly in their twenties and thirties, the ages of greatest physical and mental vigor, when people are flexible about job location and therefore help the economy adjust to changing conditions. As of the late 1970's, while 32.5 per cent of the U.S. population belongs to the 20-39 age bracket, 46.3 per cent of the immigrant cohort belongs to that prime bracket. And among immigrants who are admitted on the basis of their occupations rather than their family connections, fully 61.6 per cent are age 20-39. In addition to being young and vigorous, the immigrants possess higher education and professional capabilities in greater proportions than does the native labor force. In 1980, some 16 percent of employed natives were professional and technical workers. The corresponding figure for recent immigrants was 26 percent. Immigrants surely are not poor with respect to their earning potential. page 1/article9 immhstry/February 16, 1990